ICANN ICANN Email List Archives

[economic-framework]


<<< Chronological Index >>>    <<< Thread Index >>>

Comments on the recently published Economic Framework (Part 1)

  • To: economic-framework@xxxxxxxxx
  • Subject: Comments on the recently published Economic Framework (Part 1)
  • From: Paul Tattersfield <gpmgroup@xxxxxxxxx>
  • Date: Wed, 21 Jul 2010 23:23:03 +0100

Jul 21st, 2010


Dear Sirs,

Please find attached our comments regarding the recently published Economic
Framework for the Analysis of the Expansion of Generic Top-Level Domain
Names.

Thank you for considering our comments.



Yours faithfully,





Paul Tattersfield

http://www.gpmgroup.com

* *

* *

This latest economic report posted 16th June 2010 is an improvement over the
2009 reports from Professor Carlton, however we believe the current report
still has not touched on fundamental issues and concerns which are likely to
bedevil the proposed GNSO new gTLD process if there is an attempt to
implement it in its current form.


Given this is just an initial report we hope the following structural
economic concerns with the proposed GNSO new gTLD process could be studied
and redressed in the second part of the report.



 *Introducing competition to registry services*
*What is the economic function of a registry?
**Dangerous assumptions in the existing GNSO proposal for new gTLDs*
*Externalities for registrants in existing gTLDs not considering purchasing
new gTLDs*
*Why are new gTLD categories so important?*
*Corporate & Brand gTLDs*

*The Creation of a Super league*
*The Creation of Private Monopolies



**Introducing competition to registry services*

One way of establishing competition is to allocate the rights to run a
registry for a fixed term and on expiry of that term hold an invitation to
tender for a subsequent term.

The alternative approach to registry competition which the GNSO seems to be
trying to adopt is to award a gTLD to a registry in perpetuity and then try
and generate the competition, sort under the various MOUs, by awarding new
additional gTLDs to competing registry companies.

Given the first mover advantage of .com with 25 years of usage, the network
effect and 88,000,000 domains there has to be serious questions as to the
likely success of this approach especially when compared with a much less
complex approach involving fixed term competitive tendering of any new and
existing registries.

Further not subjecting the incumbent registries to periodic tendering of
services especially ones which may dominate the market as a whole runs the
risk of leaving both ICANN and the companies operating these registries open
to accusations of combination or conspiracy to monopolize.

For example the United States Courts of appeals ruling filed June 5, 2009
Coalition for ICANN Transparency Inc. v. VeriSign Inc. and the recent
referral at appeal raise some of these concerns. How long will it be before
ICANN is embroiled in these actions?

Many of these problems stem from the failure to clearly and publicly
articulate the fundamental principles of domain ownership and registry
function.



*What is the economic function of a registry?
*
Is a registry like a librarian whose function is to maintain a list of
books, provide access to those books at a fixed rental price and in the most
reliable and efficient manner?



Or is a registry like a book business where it aims to obtain and then
supply books at the highest prices the market will support? Perhaps by
charging people more to rent the most popular books, perhaps running
auctions and incentives in order to transact as many books as possible?



The market will recognize the “librarian model” even if ICANN does not,
quickly and effectively ensuring that in a very short space of time the
actual heavy lifting and mechanics of registrations will in the main be
contracted out to a handful of specialist registry companies like VeriSign,
Afilias & NeuStar.

This is already happening with a handful of specialist companies providing
the actual registry services.

.com .name and .net (VeriSign)

.biz .travel and .tel (NeuStar)
.aero .asia, .info mobi and .org (Afilias)

Part of this process will almost certainly lead to further consolidation,
with larger players acquiring not only the technical services of the newer
smaller registries but also the whole businesses as demonstrated with
VeriSign’s acquisition of .name and Afilias’s more recent acquisition of
.mobi

 Rather than introducing competition the GNSO proposal for new gTLDs could
be more akin to licensing contracted parties rights to sell more product
lines.



*Dangerous assumptions in the GNSO proposal for new gTLDs*

 From the outset the various Draft Applicant Guidebooks (DAGs) have presented
many issues as ready for implementation. What may seem relatively minor
issues in the overall scheme of the project to introduce new gTLDs to
improve the Domain Name System (DNS) can have massive economic implications
for virtually every user and future user of the Internet.

After the initial public reaction to the first DAG ICANN presented the four
overarching issues – Trademark Protection, Malicious Conduct, Security &
Stability: Root Scaling and TLD Demand and Economic Analysis. Later a fifth
issue - Vertical Integration of Registries and Registrars was introduced.
Vertical Integration is really just a single sub-issue from one of several
wider economic implications of introducing new gTLDs.



The early DAGs sort to make Vertical Integration as a given and simply
presented Vertical Integration as the natural solution as to how new gTLDs
should be implemented.



It subsequently became apparent that this seemingly innocuous proposal would
almost certainly lead to massive gaming of the implementation of new gTLDs
primarily to the benefit of certain contracted parties. The Board then
effectively reversed the DAG position and a GNSO Vertical Integration
working group (VI WG) was set up to seek consensus on any amendments to the
Board’s position on implementation.

The nature of the participation in the GNSO VI WG is of particular interest
because the majority of the participants are contracted or “would be”
contracted parties and as a consequence they are directly economically
impacted (both for significant benefits and losses) from how this issue is
resolved.



Because the VI economic impacts are more immediate to their personal and
business interests than many of the other economic impacts from new gTLDs
the issue has been subject to vigorous discussion with the extensive
articulation of positions seeking to draw any final proposals towards
preferred positions. This has led to over 3000 email posts on the VI WG
mailing list even before the Draft Initial Report has been issued and
without any significant signs of consensus being achieved for the initial
report.

The proposals from the GNSO for new gTLDs and subsequent DAGs contain far
greater economic impacts for the Internet as whole. It is therefore vital
that the second part of the Economic Analysis reports identify these wider
economic impacts thereby enabling ICANN and the wider community as a whole
to begin to understand, (as the contracted parties have with their interests
in VI) just how involved and far reaching some of the seemingly innocuous
concepts behind the GNSO proposal for new gTLD process actually are.


In the same way the original GNSO proposal for new gTLDs “assumed” vertical
integration was how new gTLDs should be implemented, many of the implicit
assumptions for implementing new gTLDs have been drawn up by committees
dominated by contracted parties. There are fundamental questions that need
to be redressed at a much higher level before delving into the  details,
such as the costs and benefits of defensive registrations etc.

For example: A commendable tenet of the original GNSO proposal for new gTLDs
was that existing incumbents should not be allowed to prevent entry.
Subsequently a principal was articulated that ICANN should not, for a number
of reasons, including transparency, be in the business of picking winners
and losers from applicants for new gTLDs.



The assumption that these two ideas should simply be combined in the name of
equal competition (“entry” as termed by Professor Carlton in his earlier
economic reports) whilst convenient for the interests of contracted parties
is not in the wider public interest and has led to many of the issues which
have delayed the new gTLD process.

The economic impacts of this approach far outweigh the discussion of the VI
WG but as yet there has been a noticeable absence of discussion on the
matter. This absence of consideration by the wider ICANN community runs the
risk of irreversibly damaging the DNS.


We spent a great deal of time responding to individual issues and points in
the Public Comment period for the Final Carlton Report.

Our comments
http://forum.icann.org/lists/competition-pricing-final/msg00014.html



However we see little mention of these and other issues raised during the
public comment period.
There has never been a publicly posted summary of these comments [as of July
21, 2010] and this may explain why the authors of this first part of this
current economic report do not discuss these issues in depth.
http://forum.icann.org/lists/competition-pricing-final/



 *
Externalities for registrants in existing gTLDs not considering purchasing
new gTLDs*

A further well intentioned notion is that new entrants to the gTLD registry
market will not have economic power and therefore should not be constrained
with price caps. Whilst a commendable goal it should be noted that new gTLDs
are proposed as an addition to an existing system and indeed proposed as an
addition to probably the most successful system in the history of mankind.



As an existing system existing contracted parties are subject to existing
rules and frameworks. One of the key tenets of this existing framework is
that all contracted parties should be treated equally. This means if new
gTLDs are launched without price caps on the principle they do not enjoy
market power and given existing registries do not all enjoy the same level
market power, smaller existing registries which consider themselves to have
less market power than larger incumbents are likely to apply to have their
price caps lifted.

This has the potential to introduce massive externalities for existing
innocent third parties.



The removal of price caps also raises the issue of differential pricing.
i.e. dinghy.xyz is likely to be considered more valuable than yacht.xyz.
Again if all registries have to be treated equally this introduces the
possibilities of massive externalities for registrants in existing gTLDs
simply because of the GNSO’s desire to introduce new gTLDs to give the
somewhat questionable appearance of competition in the gTLD space.



Even if restrictions on differential pricing are introduced in the live
periods there can be substantial economic impacts during sunrise launches
where businesses and mark holders operating in other gTLDs feel the need to
protect their marks defensively. A substantial number of new gTLDs launching
vastly increases the magnitude of these externalities.







*Why are new gTLD categories so important?*

It is clear from various website (including sites like
http://www.newtlds.tv/ mention in the first part fo the report) around the
Internet where people are discussing possible applications for new gTLDs
that applications for new gTLDs are likely to be clustered around several
distinct purposes

IDN – (International Domain names (Languages not based on ASCII characters)
Geographic - (.nyc .berlin)
Community & language - (.scot .cym)
Technical & Innovative - (.tel conversions for telephone numbers & domains
etc.)
Corporate & Brand - (.canon)*
Generic - (.news .shop .site)

*.canon is the only corporation we are aware of so far to express an
interest in a .brand gTLD


The whole of GNSO proposal for new gTLD implementation evolves around trying
to develop a single framework for all types of gTLD. Since the initial DAG,
there has been a reluctance to discuss or amend the one size fits all
approach which is very concerning for a bottom up or consensus driven
organization. It is clear even to the uninformed observer that each category
will introduce markedly different externalities and provide markedly
different levels of social benefits.

Further this approach leads to the impression at least that ICANN has been
captured by vested interests and the new gTLD process will implemented as a
one size fits all regardless of community concerns. The one size fits all
approach is convenient as the demand for new gTLDs is unlikely to be
uniform, indeed much of demonstrable need for new gTLDs could be satisfied
by concentrating on specific needs.

By continuing to adopt a one size fits all approach for all new gTLDs ICANN
is missing a huge opportunity to shape the proposed introduction of new
gTLDs for the public interest. Without categories the new gTLD framework has
to be far more constrained to cover for eventualities many of which have
absolutely no bearing on all but one category and therefore introduce
needless regulation and needless complexity for other categories.

The only area of the VI discussions to reach a limited form of consensus
ironically was to provide exemptions for the most economically advantaged
group of would be new gTLD applicants for .brands!

Each of the likely types of gTLDs bring individual policy concerns however
two of these types have the potential to bring fundamental economic changes
to the Internet and not necessarily in a good way.



 *Corporate & Brand gTLDs*



.com isn’t sold or advertised by VeriSign. It is sold and branded implicitly
by virtually every major corporation using it day in day out across all
their communications. It’s that simple.


The success of the internet is because it delivers efficiency to the market
place. It enables anyone to reach an unfathomable number of people simply by
buying a domain name. Cost - $10 + hosting per year. Mind blowing!

 ICANN’s new gTLDs for corporations and brands changes this by taking
advantage of the efficiencies afforded by the original design of the
Internet over non internet models. And in doing so creates a super league
the cost of entry to which is $185,000 and $25,000 + hosting per year.

Recent trends in brand evolution have led to many websites both on and off
line using a more and more minimalist form

http://www.brand.com

www.brand.com
brand.com

.brand if allowed may follow



If this happens and is reinforced worldwide in corporate communications day
in day out users will quickly come to recognize that a brand to the right of
the dot is a major player and therefore by implication a brand to the left
of the dot will be perceived as a lesser brand.

The level playing field of the internet is destroyed and a super league
created.





*
The Creation of a Super league*

There has to be serious economic concerns not least because a single layer
model to the right of the dot can never replicate the complexities of
businesses around the world. Whilst initially appearing to offer more
freedom for new domains it actually offers less freedom.

For example if there is .dell .ibm what about brands like .hp? HP is
seriously disadvantaged simply because its brand is 2 letters and 2 letters
are reserved for country codes.

Or the fact that it offers a system where there can only be one organization
to the right of the dot - ever! This is a step backwards from the existing
system which by careful management of competing open generic gTLDs allows
multiple totally separate entities to each enjoy a similar level of branding
in the second level to the left of the dot.

What about organizations whose names conflict with geographic areas?
.amazon? What about organizations or brands that share a name with places
that may in the future have a need for an internet presence? .moon or
.saturn etc. What about companies whose brands are already taken like .cat?

But most importantly a Super league destroys the ability to compete on a
level playing field. At the moment to launch some software designed to
compete with Microsoft or Sun its $10 + hosting a year then it’s down to
skill and innovation.



A super league changes this and medium sized players will have to consider
whether it worth spending $185,000 + $25,000 per year with ICANN to enjoy
the same level of branding and enter the Super league. For startups and
smaller players cost of admission to this implicit branding advantage is
likely to prove prohibitive.




*The Creation of Private Monopolies*

If day to day usage and advertising of corporate bands to the right of the
dot means they enjoy competitive advantage then generic names to the right
of the dot will become to enjoy a similar branding advantage.

Generic names such as .news .shop .store .music .radio and .movie will
become to be perceived as superior. Their simple existence will allow the
creation of a series of individual worldwide monopolies which will be
awarded primarily for the benefit of the most economically advantaged.

Because of the unique signaling each gTLD brings very few gTLDs will compete
with each other but will rather provide a monopoly advantage to single
entities  (and mixed entities) to compete with businesses operating from the
second level in existing open generic gTLDs like .com.

What happens if Microsoft applies for .search? If they are granted rights to
.search how is google.search handled? Maybe Microsoft would be happy to
allocate it to Google especially if they can use shopping.seach,
images.search & video.search to point to their own search engine Bing. This
really blurs the DNS framework with the existing entities providing a recipe
for consumer confusion to be replicated in every vertical.


What happens if Rupert Murdoch purchases a controlling interest in a company
which is awarded .news?



As a case study, the award of the .jobs gTLD illustrates the problems with
awarding monopoly positions. .jobs was initially awarded to serve the jobs
industry. The original concept was simple any real world entity offering
verified services in the jobs industry could apply for *their-name*.jobs.
The concept was to provide a verified level playing field for the whole
industry. However the people running .jobs have realized that generic names
such as engineering.jobs or atlanta.jobs could generate additional revenue
and recently have applied to ICANN to have their contract amended to allow
the registering of generic names.

The Jobs industry has identified that this application fundamentally changes
the economics of their relationship with .jobs. Whereas .jobs was setup to
be run by an entity providing a service to the worldwide jobs community, the
entity running .jobs is now seeking to leverage its relationship with ICANN
to enable it to compete against the same community whose support it elicited
and required for its original application.



Several people in the industry have realized the economic implications this
change will make and there are around 300 comments objecting to the creation
of this monopoly position in the recent ICANN comments period on the request
for changes submitted by the .jobs registry.
http://forum.icann.org/lists/jobs-phased-allocation/


It will undoubtedly be argued that the application is creating “competition”
as per the simplistic notion of entry providing competition in the earlier
economic studies from Professor Carlton, but there has to be serious
questions as to the ethics of allowing ICANN to provide its own contracted
parties with advantage in their competition with all other entities in their
industry simply because of their contractual arrangements with ICANN.

Awarding a generic gTLD in any industry to an applicant based in, or
controlled by someone in the same industry, is game changing compared with
the current system which allows numerous individual entities to compete
equitably in the second level of open gTLDs and ccTLDs. Trademark Law
doesn’t allow this advantage to be conferred nor should ICANN.

Attachment: Economic reports submission.pdf
Description: Adobe PDF document



<<< Chronological Index >>>    <<< Thread Index >>>

Privacy Policy | Terms of Service | Cookies Policy